Why is ESL a problem for contemporary (EU) society?
Wednesday 11 February 2015, by
EU policy documents stress that ESL holds important long-term economic consequences (economic growth) and macro-social consequences (social cohesion). Research calculating the financial costs of ESL very convincingly supports these arguments, while there are various difficulties in quantifying the social consequences of ESL. According to critical policy approaches, this potentially narrows understanding of the problem of ESL to its economic dimension.
ESL is commonly regarded as an urgent and serious problem for both individuals and EU society as a whole. Taking different classifications into consideration, the article focuses on the medium- and long-term fiscal (economic) and social consequences of ESL. It reviews various economic studies presenting ESL as a huge obstacle to further national and EU economic growth. These studies are chiefly based on a calculation of the estimated costs (including lower tax revenues and/or higher unemployment and welfare payments and/or higher public health expenditures and/or higher police expenditures and/or higher criminal justice expenditure) per individual ESLer lifetime and range from EUR 100,000 to EUR 1 million. Studies presenting aggregate financial gains expected from reducing ESL are also referred to. In addition, the weaknesses of the methodologies used in those studies are identified (e.g. difficulties in scenario-making due to high complexity and the rapidly changing environment; the issue of fully identifying education’s causal impact on various outcomes; the lack of data for estimating both the market-recognised and social costs of ESL), which to some extent question the credibility of their results. Since it is very hard or even impossible to monetise the social effects of ESL, the article exposes this makes them less convincing policy arguments than the economic costs of ESL. Critical policy approaches (wicked problems, governance of problems, problems represented to be) are introduced, showing that policy problems are not neutral but political and social constructs, thereby questioning the dominant (economic) understanding of the ESL problem. Within this framework, the article concludes that investments made in reducing ESL should not be only valued in terms of significant long-term financial savings, but that an essential component of its equally important, albeit in research less convincing, and visible contribution to a socially-cohesive EU society should also be taken into account.
[1] Psacharopoulos (2007) explains there is also a considerable overlap among the (private, social and fiscal) consequences of ESL. For example, a low level of education can limit employment opportunities and the earnings potential of ESLers, thereby leading to lower income tax payments and an increased risk of needing social benefits and participating in different welfare programmes (European Commission, n.d.).
[2] For example, Levin (2009) demonstrated that delivering successful preventive programmes in the area of completing upper secondary education in the USA brings benefits (USD 209,000) that are up to 2.5 times greater than the cost of intervening per graduate (between USD 59,000 and USD 143,600).
[3] Green et al. (2004) report that the macrosocial concept receives much attention in sociological theories but there is a lack of attention to it in educational research.
[4] 1) What’s the ‘problem’ /…/ represented to be in a specific policy or policy proposal? 2) What presuppositions or assumptions underpin this representation of the ‘problem’? 3) How has this representation of the ‘problem’ come about? 4) What is left unproblematic in this problem representation? Where are the silences? Can the ‘problem’ be thought about differently? 5) What effects are produced by this representation of the ‘problem’? 6) How/where has this representation of the ‘problem’ been produced, disseminated and defended? How has it been (or could it be) questioned, disrupted and replaced?
[5] The inferior position of the social dimension of education in general is also evident from selected OECD and EU policy documents. The OECD (2011, p. 58) claims that social inclusion is both a desirable end in itself and a means to achieve development outcomes like growth, and question whether social cohesion, beyond its intrinsic desirability, actually has a use, e.g. an economic pay-off. The European Commission (2006) explains that investing in education and training in order to raise efficiency and quality produces social benefits which, in turn, feed economic growth.
Bacchi, C. (2009). Analysing Policy: What’s the Problem Represented to Be? Frenchs Forest, New South Wales: Pearson Education.
Ball, J. S. (2003). The teacher’s soul and the terrors of performativity. Journal of Education Policy, 18(2), 215–228.
Beirn, R. (1972). Antecedents and consequences of early school leaving. Geneva: International Bureau of Education.
Belfield, C. R., & Levin, H. M. (Eds.). (2007). The price we pay: Economic and social consequences of inadequate education. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Belfield, C. (2008). The cost of early school-leaving and school failure. Research prepared for the World Bank. New York: Queens College, City University of New York.
Brunello, G. & De Paola, M. (2013). The costs of early school leaving in Europe. EENEE Analytical Report No. 17. Brussels: European Commission.
Business Council of Australia (2003). The cost of dropping out: The economic impact of early school leaving. Dusseldorf Skills Forum and Applied Economics.
Calero, J. & Gil-Izquierdo, M. (2014). Too much to pay: An estimation through microsimulation techniques of the monetary costs of early school leaving in Spain. Journal of Simulation, 8(4), 314–324.
Canadian Council on Learning (2009). No “drop” in the bucket: The high costs of dropping out. Retrieved from http://en.copian.ca/library/research/ccl/lessons_learning/no_drop_bucket/no_drop_bucket.pdf.
Catterall, J. C. (2011). The societal benefits and costs of school dropout recovery. Education Research International.
Chaplin, D., & Lerman, B. (1997). Dropping out: Public and private costs. Washington: The Urban Institute.
Cohen, M. (1998). The monetary value of saving a high-risk youth. Journal of Quantitative Criminology, 14(1), 5.
Colebatch, K. Hall. (2006). What work makes policy? Policy Sciences, 39(4), 309–321.
Council of Europe (2008). Report of high-level task force on social cohesion. Towards an active, fair and socially cohesive Europe. Strasbourg: Council of Europe.
Council of the EU (2011). Council Recommendation on policies to reduce early school leaving. Retrieved from http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:32011H0701(01)&from=EN.
Council of the EU (2015). Council conclusions on reducing early school leaving and promoting success in school. Retrieved from http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52015XG1215(03)&from=EN.
Dale, R. (2010). Early school leaving, lessons from research for policy makers, NESSE Report. Brussels: European Commission.
Deloitte (2012). The socio-economic benefits of investing in the prevention of early school leaving. Retrieved from http://handsonlearning.org.au/DAE_investing_in_preventing_ESL_via_HOL_September_2012.pdf
Dunn, W. N. (1981). Public policy analysis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Ecorys (2014). Interim evaluation of the strategic framework for European cooperation in education and training (ET 2020). Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/education_culture/more_info/evaluations/docs/education/et2020_en.pdf.
European Commission (2006). Communication from the Commission to the Council and to the European Parliament: Efficiency and Equity in European Education and Training systems. Brussels: European Commission.
European Commission (2011). Early school leaving in Europe – questions and answers. Retrieved from http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-11-52_en.htm
European Commission (2013). Reducing early school leaving: Key messages and policy support. Final Report of the Thematic Working Group on Early School Leaving. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/education/policy/strategic-framework/doc/esl-group-report_en.pdf
European Commission (n.d.). Overview and examples of costs of early school leaving in Europe. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/education_culture/repository/education/policy/strategic-framework/doc/europe-esl-costs_en.pdf
Fernandez Gutierrez, M., & Calero Martinez, J. (2014). The non-monetary costs of early school leaving: Estimation in terms of years of good health. Educacion, 17(2), 241–263.
Gillies, D. & Mifsud, D. (2016). Policy in transition: The emergence of tackling early school leaving (ESL) as EU policy priority. Journal of Education Policy, 31(6), 819–832.
Green, A., Preston, J., & Malmberg, L. E. (2004). Non-material benefits of education, training and skills at a macro level. In P. Descy and M. Tessaring (eds.), Impact of education and training. Third report on vocational training research in Europe: background report (pp. 119–177). Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.
Green, A., Preston, J., & Sabates, R. (2003). Education, equality and social cohesion: A distributional approach. Compare, 33, 453–470.
Grek, S. (2010). International organisations and the shared construction of policy ‘problems’: problematisation and change in education governance in Europe. European Educational Research Journal, 9(3), 396–406.
Grimaldi, E. (2012). Neoliberalism and the marginalisation of social justice: The making of an education policy to combat social exclusion. International Journal of Inclusive Education, 16(11), 1131–1154.
Hankivsky, O. (2008). Cost estimates of dropping out of high school in Canada. Retrieved from http://200.6.99.248/~bru487cl/files/Costofdroppingout.pdf
Hanushek, E. A., & Wößmann, L. (2010). Education and economic growth. In P. Peterson, E. Baker, & B. McGaw (Eds.). International Encyclopedia of Education (pp. 245–252). Oxford: Elsevier.
Haug, E. H. & Plant, P. (2015). The potential role of career guidance and career education in combating early school leaving. Neveléstudomány, 3, 5–15.
Hoppe, R. (2011). The governance of problems: Puzzling, powering and participation. Bristol: The Policy Press.
Human Resources Development Canada. (2000). Dropping out of High School: Definitions and Costs. Ottawa: Applied Research Branch, Strategic Policy. R-01-1E. October, 2000. Retrieved from http://www11.hrsdc.gc.ca/en/cs/sp/hrsdc/arb/publications/ research/2000-000063/page09.shtml.
Lamb, S., Dwyer, P., & Wynn, J. (2000). Noncompletion of school in Australia: The changing patterns of participation and outcomes. Camberwell, Victoria: ACER.
Lamb, S., & Huo, S. (2017). Counting the costs of lost opportunity in Australian education. Mitchell Institute report No. 02/2017. Melbourne: Mitchell Institute.
Levin, H. M. (2009). The economic payoff to investing in educational justice. Educational Researcher, 38, 5–20.
Macedo, E., Helena C., Araújo, H. C., Magalhães, A. & Rocha, C. (2015). The construction of early school leaving as a political concept under the lenses of sociology of education. Profesorado, 19(3), 28–42.
Nevala, A. M., & Hawley, J. et al. (2011). Reducing early school leaving in the EU. Study. Brussels: European Parliament.
OECD (2006). Measuring the Effects of Education on Health and Civic Engagement. Proceedings of the Copenhagen Symposium. Retrieved from https://www.oecd.org/edu/innovation-education/37437718.pdf
OECD (2010). The high cost of low educational performance. The long-run economic impact of improving PISA outcomes. Paris: OECD Publishing.
OECD (2011). Perspectives on global development 2012 social cohesion in a shifting world. Paris: OECD Publishing.
Oomen, A., & Plant, P. (2014). Early school leaving & lifelong guidance. ELGPN Concept Note No. 6. Jyväskylä: European Lifelong Guidance Policy Network.
Ozga, J. (2003). Measuring and managing performance in education. Edinburgh: University of Edinburgh: Centre for Educational Sociology (CES) Briefing No. 27.
Psacharopoulos, G. (2007). The costs of school failure – a feasibility study. European Expert Network on Economics of Education.
Rittel, H. J., & Webber, M. M. (1973). Dilemmas in the general theory of planning. Policy Science, 4, 155–169.
Roberts, N. C. (2000). Wicked problems and network approaches to resolution. International Public Management Review, 1(1), 1–19.
Ross, A., & Leathwood, C. (2013). Problematising early school leaving. European Journal of Education, 48(3), 405–418.
Smyth, J. (2010). Adolescent engagement, connectedness and dropping out of school. In J. L. DeVitis, & L. Irwin-DeVitis (Eds.), Adolescent education. A reader (pp. 195–208). New York: Peter Lang.
Sum, A., Khatiwada, I., & McLaughlin, J. (2009). The consequences of dropping out of high school: Joblessness and jailing for high school dropouts and the high cost for taxpayers. Center for Labor Market Studieublications. Paper 23. NorthEastern University.
Van Alphen, S. (2009) The educational quality of early school leavers and the cross-national variation of their income disadvantage. Educational Research and Evaluation: An International Journal on Theory and Practice, 15(6), 543–560.